What Is Proportional Representation And Its Benefits Politics Essay

Proportional representation (PR) voting systems are used by most of the world’s major democracies. Under PR, representatives are elected from multi-seat districts in proportion to the number of votes received. PR assures that political parties or candidates will have the percent of legislative seats that reflects their public support. A party or candidate need not come in first to win seats.

There's a specialist from your university waiting to help you with that essay.
Tell us what you need to have done now!


order now

In contrast, in the United States we use “winner-take-all” single seat districts, where votes going to a losing candidate are wasted, even if that candidate garners 49.9% of the vote. This leaves significant blocs of voters unrepresented. Voters sense this, and so often we do not vote for a candidate we like, but rather the one who realistically stands the best chance of winning-the “lesser of two evils.” Or, all too often, we don’t bother to vote at all.

No wonder that, among the 21 democracies in Western Europe and North America, the United States is next to last in voter turn-out, with only 36% participating in the 1994 Congressional elections.

What Are The Advantages Of PR?

Greater voter turn-out (typically 70-90%) because there are more choices for voters-third, fourth, fifth parties and more from diverse perspectives including more women and minorities elected:

41% women in Sweden

39% in Finland

36% in Norway

only 11% in the U.S.

This leads to:

more diverse representation

cleaner campaigns run on the issues, not mud-slinging

reduced effects of big money

Where In The World Is PR Used?

Some form of PR is used by most of the world’s major democracies, including:

Germany

Sweden

Switzerland

Belgium

Denmark

Holland

Greece

Spain

Austria

Australia

Mexico

Portugal

Japan

Russia

Italy

Ireland

Israel

Poland

Hungary

New Zealand

Iceland

Brazil

Nicaragua

Norway

Finland

Venezuela

and moreaˆ¦

“Winner-take-all” is still used in France, Great Britain, and a few of Britain’s former colonies that inherited it: the United States, Canada, and India.

In April 1994 South Africa became the latest nation to switch to PR. In 1993 New Zealand, Japan, Russia and Mexico adopted a form of PR. Significantly, only a few of the former Soviet Bloc countries, including Russia, have chosen to model their emerging democracies after the “winner-take-all” model. Almost all have adopted some form of PR because they recognize the obvious: PR is a fairer, more flexible, more modern electoral system than the antiquated eighteenth century “winner-take-all” method.

Is PR The Same As A Parliamentary System?

No, it isn’t. A parliamentary system is a type of governmental system, while PR is a type of voting/electoral system. One is about the structure of government, the other about how votes are counted. Many, but not all, of the countries using PR combine it with a parliamentary governmental system. But this does not have to be the case, and a PR electoral system could successfully be combined with the U.S. presidential system.

Has PR Been Tried In The U.S.?

Various forms of PR are used today to elect the city councils of Cambridge MA, Peoria IL, Alamagordo NM, various cities and counties in Alabama and Texas, the community school boards in New York City, the Democratic presidential primaries, various corporate boards, and the finalists for the Academy Awards.

The preference voting form of PR was first tried in the U.S. earlier this century. PR was first tried in the U.S. in the 1920’s and worked very well in 24 cities like New York City, Boulder, Cincinnati, Cleveland, and Cambridge, MA. Both the majority and various political and racial minorities gained representation where their voices had previously been unheard. Although only two of the first 26 attempts to repeal preference voting were successful in cities around the country, formerly dominant political forces outlasted reformers and were successful in repealing PR nearly everywhere. Their general tactic was targetting unpopular minorities like blacks and leftists.

So How Does PR Work?

There are many different types of PR, because it is a flexible system that may be adapted to the situation of any city, state or nation. Here are a few of the most common:

List System-by far the most widely used form of PR. The voter selects one party and its slate of candidates to represent them. Party slates can be either “closed” or “open,” allowing voters to indicate a preference for individual candidates. If a party receives 30% of the vote, they receive 30% of the seats in the legislature, 10% of the vote receives 10% of the seats, and so on. A minimum share of the votes can be required to earn representation; typically a 5% threshold is used. This type of PR is ideal for large legislatures on state and national levels.

Mixed Member System (MM)-This PR hybrid elects half the legislature from single-seat, “winner-take-all” districts and the other half by the List System. Mixed-member smoothly combines geographic, ideological and proportional representation.

Preference Voting (PV)-the voter simply ranks candidates in an order of preference (1,2,3,4, etcaˆ¦). Once a voter’s first choice is elected or eliminated, excess votes are “transferred” to subsequent preferences until all positions are filled. Voters can vote for their favorite candidate(s), knowing that if that candidate doesn’t receive enough votes their vote will “transfer” to their next preference. With preference voting, every vote counts and very few votes are wasted. Preference voting is ideal for non-partisan elections like city councils. This method is also called “Single Transferrable Vote” or “STV”.

What About The President? We Can’t Divide Up The Presidency, Can We?

No, we can’t. However, there are much better ways for electing officials such as president, mayor, or governor than what we use today:

Majority preference voting (MPV)-related to preference voting. Like preference voting, the voter simply ranks candidates in an order of preference (ex. 1. Perot 2. Clinton 3. Bush). The candidate with the least number of first place votes is eliminated, and their votes are “transferred” to their 2nd choice until a candidate has a majority.

Approval-Voters are allowed to vote for all candidates they approve. For example, Bush-Yes Perot-No Clinton-Yes. The candidate with the highest number of “yes” votes wins. For a more complete explanation, see http://bcn.boulder.co.us/government/approvalvote/center.html

Condorcet’s Method – Like preference voting and majority preference voting, the voter simply ranks candidates in an order of preference (ex. 1. Perot 2. Clinton 3. Bush). Unlike majority preference voting though, several two-way races are simulated using the ballots, determining who would win a Perot/Clinton race, who would win a Perot/Bush race, and who would win a Bush/Clinton race. The one who wins all of the pairwise elections wins. For a more complete explanation, see http://www.eskimo.com/~robla/politics/condorcet.html

All of these methods give voters a greater voice in how their vote is used, and alleviate the “lesser-of-two-evils” problem for voters. Our current winner-take-all system promotes candidates who blame all of our problems on those who would never vote for them, and punishes candidates who come up with pragmatic, middle-ground solutions.

Could PR Help Break The Political Impasse In The U.S. Over Important Issues Like Health Care?

Yes, it could. PR allows small parties to be a credible alternative to voters, giving them a national audience for their views to advance new ideas. PR had no ideological bias, but simply facilitates a fuller and more informed discussion of policy options; this more grounded discussion in turn provides greater opportunities to move to majority consensus on difficult issues.

An example of this is the German Greens. Without ever winning a single district election or receiving more than 10% of the national vote, the German Greens were able to see several of their environmental positions become part of a national consensus. PR allows majorities to make policy while also bringing minority perspectives to the table for consideration.

But I Like Having A Representative From My Own District. Won’t I Lose Out Without It?

A representative from your own district is nice, but with “winner-take-all” there’s a good chance you didn’t vote for that representative. In the 1994 Congressional elections, only 21% of eligible voters helped elect someone. Under PR, you will have, not one, but several representatives from a larger district. And there is a much greater likelihood that at least one of those reps will be someone you voted for. In South Africa’s 1994 PR elections, 86% of eligible voters helped elect someone.

Also, the mixed-member form of PR used by Germany can give voters the benefits of both: a representative from your district, as well as a legislature that proportionally reflects the electorate.

PR doesn’t base representation so much on geography but on political viewpoint. When our republic was young and dotted with small communities barely connected by slow communication and primitive transportation, the interests of citizens were similar to those of their neighbors. But our society is more mobile now, more multicultural and diverse. People living right next door to one another can have completely opposite viewpoints, yet with our single seat “winner-take-all” districts, only one of these voters will receive representation-the one that voted for the winner. Simple geographical representation can no longer ensure fair political representation for all voters and all political perspectives.

What’s Wrong With Only Two Parties?

Two parties limit the voters’ choices. U.S. citizens would never accept an economic system that allowed us to buy cars from only two companies, or to choose from only two airlines. Why then, should we have to settle for just two options in politics? It’s no wonder such a large portion of the U.S. electorate decides not to participate. They’re not buying what the two parties are selling!

The logjam and partisan bickering of U.S. politics is partly the result of the winner-take-all two-party system, where each party says everything they do is right and the other party does is wrong. The optimum campaign strategy is to sling mud at your opponent, driving their voters to your party. New ideas and solutions have a hard time percolating to the surface in such an environment. But this dynamic is not so advantageous when there are three or more parties.

Winner-take-all elections are also more susceptible to the corruption of big money. A majority of votes is a lot of votes to win, and a candidate has to plaster her or his name and face over every billboard, bumper sticker and TV ad. Since so much is at stake-you either win the seat or you lose-there is an urgency to spend lavishly.

But with PR you don’t have to come in first to win seats. Whatever proportion of votes your party wins, you get that many seats in the legislature. PR actually reduces the number of votes it takes for a party or candidate to win a seat. Candidates tend to run cleaner, more positive, issue-oriented campaigns, targeted at a particular constituency. Such campaigns require less money to win seats.

Could PR Help In Voting Rights Cases?

Absolutely. With PR, you actually need less votes to gain a seat than in the winner-take-all system, and you can gather these votes from a larger area. This makes it easier for racial or political minority perspectives to win seats, without having to gerrymander districts.

In June 1995, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled in Miller v. Johnson that racially gerrymandered districts are unconstitutional. Voting rights experts like Lani Guinier, Ed Still, Gerald Hebert, Pamela Karlan and Richard Engstrom have proposed various forms of PR as a race-neutral method to give racial as well as political minorities and women a fair chance to elect representatives in competitive elections.

Does PR Affect The Election of Women?

Yes, very much so. Research has shown that systems of proportional representation result in greater numbers of elected women, and that greater numbers of women are elected in multi-seat rather than single-seat districts. Women currently make up only 11% of the U.S. House of Representatives and 8% of the U.S. Senate. In state and local legislatures, women average only one out of five legislators. According to United Nation reports, the United States ranks 24th of 54 western democracies in terms of women’s representation in national legislatures. In fact, scholars have demonstrated that the underrepresentation of blacks is largely an underrepresentation of black women. African American women have only about one fourth the representation of black men.

So How Do We Change From “Winner-Take-All” To PR?

In many states it is possible to convert to PR simply by changing applicable laws. Amendments to the U.S. Constitution are not required. The laws can be changed by a simple vote of the legislatures, or in many cases via a voter initiative. PR can be adapted to local, state and national levels, bringing the democratic promise of “one person, one vote” closer to fulfillment.

If the political will could be mobilized, it is possible to convert immediately to a system of proportional representation for electing representatives to city councils, state legislatures, and even the U.S. House of Representatives. U.S. Senators could be elected by Majority Preference Voting (MPV), giving voters more choice. As a bonus, PR would spare states the torment of legislative redistricting, an arduous, bitter and partisan gerrymandering affair.